Faculty of law blogs / UNIVERSITY OF OXFORD

ECJ in Marco Tronchetti Provera v. Consob on price adjustments in mandatory bids in Case of Collusion

Author(s)

Tom Vos
Visiting Professor, Jean-Pierre Blumberg Chair at the University of Antwerp (Belgium)

Posted

Time to read

5 Minutes

In a decision of 20 July 2017 in the case Marco Tronchetti Provera SpA e.a. v Consob, the European Court of Justice ruled for the first time on the interpretation of article 5(4) of the Takeover Directive. This provision covers the possibility for the national supervisory authority of a Member State to adjust the price of a mandatory bid. In this case, the Italian supervisory authority, Consob, had decided to increase such price because it believed that there had been collusion between the bidder and one of the sellers. This price adjustment was allowed by Italian takeover law, but the bidder believed that the Italian law violated the Takeover Directive, arguing that the criteria for a price adjustment were insufficiently clear. The Court of Justice ruled, however, that the concept of collusion that is used in Italian law as one of the possible justifications for a price adjustment is not necessarily too vague. This way, the Court further clarifies the competence of national legislators to regulate the fair price in mandatory bids.

The facts of the case are important to understand the relevant legal issue. Marco Tronchetti Provera & C. SpA (MTP), an Italian company, had set up a subsidiary, Lauro 61 SpA, in order to acquire all of the shares of Camfin SpA, a holding company listed on the Milan Stock Exchange. Camfin held, amongst other participations, a participation of 26,19% in Pirelli & C. SpA.

The bidder Lauro 61 had acquired 60,99% of the shares in Camfin, after concluding transactions with many shareholders of Camfin, including Malacalza Investimenti Srl (‘MCI’). Lauro 61 was thus required to launch a mandatory bid, as the threshold under Italian law of 30% of the shares had been crossed. In accordance with Italian law, the price of the mandatory bid was EUR 0,80 per share, the highest price that had been paid over the previous 12 months.

However, minority shareholders of Camfin complained with Consob, which decided to increase the price of the mandatory bid because of collusion between the bidder and the selling shareholders. The reason for this was a shareholders’ agreement (including a lock-up provision) between MTP, Lauro 61, MCI and some of the larger shareholders of Camfin. MCI had sold its shares in Camfin to the bidders at a price of EUR 0,80 per share, but had also bought a participation of 6,98% in Pirelli from two of the other signatories to the shareholders’ agreement at a price of EUR 7,80 per share, even though the market value of those shares was EUR 8,00 per share. Consob decided that this was a case of collusion, because Lauro 61 (and parties acting in concert with it) had approved the release of the shares from the lock-up arrangement under the shareholders’ agreement, so that they could be sold to MCI. Hence, Consob held that the lower price for the Pirelli shares constituted an extra advantage for MCI, which should be reflected in an increase of the price of the mandatory bid to EUR 0,83 per share.

Indeed, according to article 5(4) of the Takeover Directive, the price of a mandatory bid shall be regarded as equitable if it is equal to the highest price paid for the same securities by the offeror, or by persons acting in concert with him/her, over a period, to be determined by Member States, of not less than six months and not more than 12 before the bid.’

However, the second paragraph of article 5(4) contains an exception to the ‘highest price paid rule’, laying down the conditions for a price adjustment, as well as some non-exhaustive examples: Member States may authorise their supervisory authorities to adjust the price referred to in the first subparagraph in circumstances and in accordance with criteria that are clearly determined. To that end, they may draw up a list of circumstances in which the highest price may be adjusted either upwards or downwards, for example where the highest price was set by agreement between the purchaser and a seller, […].’ (own emphasis).

This possibility has been implemented in Italian law. Article 106(3)(d) of the ‘Decreto legislativo nr. 58’ stipulates that the Consob can increase the bid price in a mandatory bid, if certain circumstances are present, including in the case of collusion between the bidder (or the persons acting in concert with the bidder) and one or more of the sellers. In the case at hand, however, it was not clear whether the parties to the side-agreement intended to collude (as mentioned by AG Wahl in his opinion).

The referring Italian court clarified that the requirement of collusion does not require the minority shareholders to prove an element of intent or fraud, even though this is required under the definition of ‘collusion’ in other fields of law. The bidders and concerted parties argued that this interpretation of ‘collusion’ is too vague and gives the Consob an unlimited degree of discretion, which violates the requirement in article 5(4) that the criteria for the price adjustment are ‘clearly determined’. Basically, this argument boils down to the same argument used against every anti-abuse rule (which article 5(4) clearly is): ‘it harms legal certainty.’

The Court of Justice struck down the arguments of the bidders. The Court agreed with the Advocate General that the requirement that the criteria are clearly determined does not preclude member states from using abstract legal concepts, such as ‘collusion’. Here, the Court recognizes that every anti-abuse rule features some degree of open-endedness, which is necessary precisely to prevent circumvention of the rule. Second, the Court ruled that the fact that a concept such as ‘collusion’ has another meaning in other fields of law (for example in competition law), does not mean that it is not ‘clearly determined’. The Court leaves the final decision of whether the notion of collusion is sufficiently clear to determination by the Italian court, ‘using methods of interpretation recognised by the national law’. But the wording of the decision seems to suggest that the Court does consider the Italian provisions sufficiently clear. This is contrary to the opinion of AG Wahl, who seemed to consider the fact that there were doubts on how the concept of collusion should be interpreted under Italian law as evidence that the provision was not sufficiently clear.

In conclusion, the decision of the Court of Justice provides a nice illustration of the provisions on price adjustments in mandatory bids. In essence, these provisions aim to ensure that minority shareholders receive an equitable price. In the case at hand, the bidders (and parties acting in concert with them) and one of the selling shareholders (MCI) concluded a side-agreement, without any evidence that this occurred in bad faith. Nevertheless, the agreement did have an impact on the fairness of the price, so that a price adjustment was justified. The Italian rules provided this option, and the Court of Justice held that this was in accordance with the Takeover Directive.

This is good news for other European countries with similar rules. For example, under article 55 of the Belgian Takeover Decree, a price adjustment by the Financial Services and Markets Authority (‘FSMA’) is possible when ‘additional economic benefits are awarded to some of the selling shareholders’, which allows for a similar solution as under the Italian rule. Similarly, under article 234-6 of the General Regulation of the French Authorité des Marchés Financiers (‘AMF’), a price increase by the AMF is possible in case of a related transaction between the bidder and the selling shareholders (amongst other circumstances).

In the United Kingdom, on the other hand, note 3 on rule 9.5 of the Takeover Code only contains a list of ‘circumstances which the Panel might take into account when considering an adjustment of the highest price’. In the Netherlands, the criteria are even vaguer: article 5:80b of the Financial Supervision Act simply states that the takeover price can be adjusted if this is necessary to reach an ‘equitable price’ (‘billijke prijs’), without giving further guidance. One can wonder whether these legal regimes for price adjustments in mandatory bids are ‘sufficiently clear’, as required by the article 5(4) of the Takeover Directive.

The decision discussed in this post indicates that the Court of Justice does not take a very stringent view on this issue, as long as the interpretation of the provisions is clear under the methods of national law (which seem to allow room for further interpretation by national courts and supervisory authorities). Still, with an open-ended provision such as article 5(4) of the Takeover Directive, and its national implementations, which are intended as anti-abuse rules that ensure a fair takeover price, there is an inherent tension between achieving this objective and legal certainty. Only further applications of these rules can give more guidance on how this tension will be resolved.

Another version of this blogpost appeared earlier on Corporate Finance Lab.

Tom Vos is PhD Candidate at the Jan Ronse Institute of Company and Financial Law at the University of Leuven.

Share

With the support of